[NOTICE TO READERS: For five years, Reid's Reader has been presenting an entirely free service to readers with commentary on books new and old. Reid's Reader
receives no grants or subsidies and is produced each week in many hours
of unpaid work. If you wish to contribute, on an entirely voluntary
basis, to the upkeep of this blog, we would be very grateful if you made
a donation via the PayPal "DONATE" button that now appears at the top
of the index at right. Thank you.]
We feature each week Nicholas Reid's reviews and comments on new and recent books.
“THE BROKEN DECADE – Prosperity, Depression
and Recovery in New Zealand 1928-39” by Malcolm McKinnon (Otago University
Press, $49:95)
As
I’ve argued elsewhere on this blog, revisionism is the life-blood of the
academic study of History and so it should be. As we move in time further away
from historical events, we rightly see them in a different perspective and are
more aware of their long-term consequences. New history books have to be
written. As relevant new documents and other evidence come to light, received
opinions on a given era must be challenged. New history books have to be
written. When memoirs and works of fiction have created a “legend” or popular
image about a certain period, it is right for historians to lay before us the
best available factual evidence. New history books have to be written. Of
course some history books are unnecessary (especially many “popularisations”,
which tend merely to re-hash more scholarly works). But the task of “rewriting
history” is exactly what good historians should be undertaking.
Malcolm McKinnon
(formerly of Victoria University of Wellington) is a good, thorough and
conscientious historian. The 512 closely-printed pages of his The Broken Decade consist of 420 pages
of densely-reasoned and documented text followed by 92 pages of substantiating
notes. I must also add that as a physical object, this is one of the heaviest
books I have ever encountered, being all printed on thick glossy pages, perhaps
the better to accommodate the illustrations and graphs. This is not a light
read in any sense of the term.
Nowhere does
McKinnon pronounce himself to be a revisionist, but it is clear from his
introduction that he is less than satisfied with those books that have so far
been written about New Zealand’s experience of economic depression in the
1930s.
He name-checks various popular books on the
subject, but makes special mention of Tony Simpson’s “oral history” The Sugarbag Years, basically a
collection of recorded interviews with people who had lived through the 1930s.
McKinnon says of The Sugarbag Years
that it is “the study that more than any other…
cited by contemporary New Zealanders when ‘the Depression of the 1930s’ is
mentioned.” He continues by
remarking that The Broken Decade “does
not replace [The Sugarbag Years]; it is more in the nature of a conversation
with it.” (p.8) Nevertheless, McKinnon is uncomfortable with the legend,
which “treats the Depression as a
conflict between rich and poor, the powerful and the powerless, in which the
‘little guy’ finally wins, or appears to. The win draws a line not just under
the Depression but under the era of conservative or ‘not very liberal’
governments since 1906, when Seddon died.” (p.19) According to this legend,
the election of the Labour government in 1935 spelled the end of old-fashioned laissez-faire
liberalism and the acceptance of collectivist government intervention.
In fact, argues
McKinnon, in his 1928-30 government, the old Liberal Sir Joseph Ward’s “combination
of state-directed expansion and wage-earner and other kinds of sectional
welfare was a potent mix that Labour replicated – even if it did not
acknowledge this – when it gained power in 1935.” (p.22) Labour may have
restored and then expanded some of the benefits that were established in the
1920s, culminating in the Social Security Act of 1938, “although in practice it was the full employment of the workforce… that
was central to its strategy and that relied on public works and house-building as
in the 1920s.” (p.26)
Therefore
McKinnon’s basic argument is that the agony of the Depression in New Zealand was
not a case of hidebound conservative politicians (in the United-Reform Coalition)
refusing to find a way out of the Slump. Much of Labour policy had been pioneered
before, especially by Ward. Labour did not represent progress so much as
attempt to regain former prosperity and re-work familiar remedies.
McKinnon
returns to the clear articulation of this general thesis in his final chapter (Chapter
11), where he considers the “legacy” of New Zealand’s Depression, and once
again untangles (pp.396-401) the standard received views before considering
(pp.401 ff.) more recent scholarship, which has modified the legend of years of
universal misery. As he notes:
“The ‘sugarbagging’ of the Depression gave a
particular contour to the memory of it. It was not inaccurate but it was
partial, in the sense that it shaded out the experiences of hundreds of
thousands of people who were affected by the Depression but were not as damaged
by it as those who lost jobs, houses or livelihood.” (p.401)
None of this is
to claim was there was not huge
hardship in unemployment, evictions, widespread poverty, niggardly sustenance
and relief work. But there are persistent myths, which McKinnon proceeds to
disprove, such as the one that New Zealand relief workers were harnessed like
horses to drag harrows or that there were “slave” camps. Farmers did
walk off the land with mortgages they were unable to pay, but as McKinnon
shows, the peak of this happened in the 1920s before the Depression struck.
Child labour was common on farms, but then it was common from 1919 to 1939,
both before and after the Depression.
Thus much for
the “bookends” of this very substantial book – its clear revisionism and the
idea of continuity that McKinnon
wishes to stress. McKinnon is further insistent in his introduction that the
experience of the Depression was not all of a piece – it went in phases.
And it is with these
that the bulk of the book deals – ten chapters which chart the changes in
emphases, mood and political choices in the years 1928-39. As a warning to his
readers, McKinnon makes it clear that The
Broken Decade deliberately focuses, not on the experiences of individuals,
but on politics and finance. This is not an anecdotal account of hardships.
It plays thus:
First there was (Chapter
1) the “Indian summer” of the 15 months (1928-30) of Sir Joseph Ward’s
premiership and his efficient dealing with benefits and also with growth-geared
economy. Even by the middle of 1930 (when the Slump was already felt in the rest
of world), effects in New Zealand still seemed relatively minor. It was simply
like a replay of the minor downturn in the mid-1920s, and George Forbes’ first
budget dealt with it in those terms. Then (Chapter 2) came the real bite of
full economic depression in 1930-32. When Ward was prime minister, his United
Party government was kept in power with the support of Labour votes.
Now that
Forbes was prime minister and pursuing austerity policies, Labour moved away as
Reform and United got closer. Even so, Labour still supported deflation and the
need to balance the budget. Gordon Coates (Reform) and Forbes (United) moved to
a “fusion”, without their respective parties actually uniting. This meant that
before the 1931 election, Labour became the official opposition. But the election
of 1931 cemented the Reform-United Coalition’s position and consensus was now
moving towards the view that raising loans was not the best way to run an
economy in times when the loans would be impossible to repay.
By 1932 (Chapter
3), New Zealanders were puzzled that the austerity policies of the Coalition
took so long to rein in rents and interest rates as well as wages and salaries…
but now the Coalition moved into cutting pensions, education votes and existing
benefits. When it came to taking the teeth out of the Industrial Conciliation
and Arbitration Act, Labour was most vociferous in opposing. Says McKinnon:
“All three political parties endorsed
austerity, although Labour was completely at odds with the others over how
to deal with it; the battleground was that of obligations and entitlements
rather than expansion or austerity. Different segments of opinion within Reform
and United were also often at odds with each other, for instance over the
extent to which contractual obligations, such as pensions, could be diluted.”
(p.107)
But
while austerity and balancing the books were orthodoxy for all parties, there
was (Chapter 3) a parallel crisis going on with unemployment in 1930-32. The
long attempt to avoid outright and general payment of a dole meant various
schemes for paid relief work. The new system of funding relief work, by special
taxation levy, had been endorsed by Labour in late 1920s, before the slump hit.
Unemployment figures were rising in 1931, and McKinnon comments “In retrospect it seems remarkable that the
difficult circumstances through 1931 did not lead to outbursts on the scale of
those that took place in 1932. There was certainly no lack of evidence of hard
times or troubled lives.” (p.123)
Why was the
public reaction so muted? McKinnon speaks of the “cushion” provided by people’s
savings, which were used up by 1932, and also what he cites Margaret Tennant as
calling “the informal side of the welfare
economy” (p.129) – that is, there were quite a number of caring bosses who
provided for workers at their own expense; there was much practical welfare
provided by churches; and local councils and hospital boards decided to keep
the social peace as much as possible by making as generous provision for the
unemployed as they could. Hence demonstrations of the unemployed in 1931 would
attract a few hundred people rather than the thousands that they attracted in
1932. But employment continued to rise. And most government schemes to
alleviate it involved rural work, though the great majority of the unemployed
were in the main cities. The Labour party and the trade unions focused on
ensuring that wages and conditions were maintained for the employed, knowing
that many employers could use the threat of unemployment to lower wages.
It is in this
context that McKinnon cites many instances of personal distress, with stories
and personal testimony as wrenching as anything found in The Sugarbag Years.
Gordon Coates’
immediate plan was to defuse tensions in the cities by moving unemployed men
(especially unmarried men) to public works camps in the country. But there was
much dissent about this, the heat was raised, and now there really were serious
riots and disturbances in Dunedin, Christchurch, Wellington, and Auckland, with
the largest being the major (and much mythologised) riot in Auckland in April
1932. However (Chapter 4) despite common legend, the riots and disturbances in
Auckland and elsewhere did not lead to a period of prolonged alarm. After a few
weeks of panic the “special” constables were stood down, although local
ordinances still banned outdoors meetings. Few unemployed men were willing to
take up the option of going to public work camps. Then there was the matter of
women not being properly represented in the statistics of unemployment; and of
evictions especially from State Advances houses, even though in April 1932, the
government had reduced rents by 20%. The peak of unemployment was April 1933.
Thereafter there was a slow decline as the economy picked up. In all this there
was the special problem of youth unemployment, partly because of the “extreme reluctance of unions, in the
weakened labour market, to encourage youth competition with adult workers.”
(p.189)
As McKinnon is
always ready to remind us, all New Zealand’s hardships took place within the
context of the government attempting to find financial solutions to the effects
of the slump; trying to find better prices for New Zealand exports; trying to
stimulate the economy to create real employment and trying to find the hard
cash that could pay for needed welfare. In 1932-33 (Chapter 5, entitled “How to
Raise Prices”), after the Ottawa conference, there was the prospect of
“reflating” (i.e. slightly inflating) currency in the hope of profiting more
from exports to Britain. The National Expenditure Commission released a report in
September 1931 advocated huge cuts to education and all social services and a
drastic reduction in the number of hospital boards. Labour raged against in in
parliament, with Labour leader Harry Holland calling it “An utterly valueless document to the country… the commissioners
attacked the human being from the cradle to the grave.” (p.202). But
McKinnon points out that all parliamentary
political parties repudiated the report. However, spending on public works was
drastically reduced. It had been 4.8 million pounds in 1931-32 but was only 1.7
million pound in 1932-33. Public works in effect became a relief agency and its
workers were paid relief rates. By this stage in the depression there were many
plans for monetary reform, only some of which were Douglas Social Credit.
Keynesianism was now beginning to have an influence on some New Zealand
economic thinking. McKinnon notes that once again Labour was often in agreement
with the (otherwise conservative) Farmers’ Union on these matters.
The main
discussion within the governing parties was about what to do with the exchange
rate. After a major tussle in the cabinet between Downie Stewart and Gordon
Coates, the government raised the exchange rate in its first inflationary move.
(Chapter 6) This move was popular at first
with rural New Zealand, but was fiercely criticised by both business and
labour, with their separate fears of rising prices or rising wages. The ephemeral
New Zealand Legion, with its vague ideas, was strongly anti-Keynesian.
In 1933 there
was further agitation against married men being drafted into rural public works
camps. McKinnon refutes the claim made the Keith Sinclair (cited p.239) that “few people outside the Labour Party lent an
ear to Keynes’ plea for increased government expenditure”. Many other
groups were now adopting Keynesian ideas. However, Labour was now (for the
first time) articulating its own fiscal policy in it electioneering document “Labour
Has A Plan” (1933). McKinnon sums up the Reform-United coalitions conservative,
but prudent, fiscal policy thus:
“It remained wedded to financing unemployment
relief through the tax system, avoiding either borrowing or ‘inflationary’ credit
expansion. The exchange rate aside, lower interest rates remained its favoured
means of stimulating economic activity and employment by the private sector.
Its objections to the measures proposed by its critics were not unfounded.”
(p.253)
By late 1933 (Chapter
7) there seemed to be a rise in commodity prices, but this tended to be
confined to the agricultural sector; and there was still a failure to adjust
credit rating appropriately. When it came to credit matters and radical ideas
of currency reform, Major Douglas’s visit to New Zealand in 1934 was a flop and
the Social Credit movement peaked and went into decline as an influence on
major political parties. By this stage, Labour found common cause with smaller
businesses and consumers and was now clearly in favour of only a limited degree
of government control of private businesses. The Reserve Bank at last opened August
1934
By this stage
(1933-34, Chapter 8) it was clear that the consensus of all parliamentary
political parties was moving towards acceptance of what would come to be known
as the “welfare state”, with expanded benefits and national health insurance,
especially as these measures had already been carried in some Australian
states, in Britain and in the New Deal in the USA. As unemployment lessened,
there were still polemical struggles concerning the unemployed, especially in
the matter of sustenance (rather than relief work). These pitted the Unemployed
Workers’ Movement (UWM), controlled by the tiny and electorally insignificant
Communist Party, against the more practical Labour-oriented Unemployed Workers
Association (UWA). But parallel with agitation concerning the unemployed, there
was unrest among the employed, calling for the restoration of cut wages and the
restoration of compulsory arbitration in industrial disputes. In itself this
was evidence that the worst of the depression was over. Gordon Coates’ budgets
of 1934-35 began to restore cuts as economic situation improved.
Making a general
statement about the hardships of New Zealanders in the Depression, Malcolm
McKinnon remarks:
“The plight of the poor and deprived was all
the more pronounced because the Depression had not had a marked impact on the
health and wellbeing of the population as a whole. Significant indicators of
deprivation – infant mortality, maternal mortality, the incidence of
tuberculosis, child malnutrition – did not rise in the early 1930s.”
(p.315)
Nor did the
annual number of suicides rise; but there was an increased mortality rate of
women from septic abortions, and the higher rate of Maori infant mortality
continued to cause concern, as it had done in the 1920s.
By mid-1935,
with the election looming, the Coalition government scrambled to outbid Labour
and most pre-Depression pensions and benefits were restored to their full rates.
And so at last
to the 1935 election (Chapter 9). McKinnon plunges us into the thick of it by
reminding us in minute detail of how the election campaigns were actually
fought, rather than simply cutting to the Labour victory. As he notes in
detail, it is often forgotten that in 1935, both the Coalition and Labour
feared the possible “spoiler” effect of the newly-formed Democrat Party. Labour
and the Coalition were afraid that the Democrats would do what the United Party
had done in 1928, and damage two established parties enough to gain the
treasury benches. In the effect, the Democrats fizzled into nothingness in the
election itself, but both Labour and the Coalition campaigned against them.
McKinnon is also
insistent that the main issues of the election were about economics, not about
social welfare:
“While the first Labour government is
remembered, more than anything, for legislating for social security in 1938,
social welfare was the least contested field of the 1935 election campaign.
This reflected both the extent of absorption in and debate and argument over
money and finance on the one hand, and a consensus among political parties on
health and social insurance on the other – with persistent debate about how it
should be financed.” (pp.330-331)
Labour’s
policies in the 1935 campaign were unclear and its fiscal stance not too far
from orthodoxy. Like the Coalition, Labour was gearing for a recovery economy.
In considering
how Labour performed in office 1935-39 (Chapter 10), McKinnon argues that in
practice Labour’s programme was one of restoration as were its fiscal policies.
Much depended on a reversion to more borrowing from London (as under the Ward
government), signalled by the finance minister Walter Nash’s visits there. However,
the Labour government did enhance nearly all benefits or pensions.
Labour won the 1938 election with a real
absolute majority (they had won 46.1% of the popular vote in 1935; they won
55.8% in 1938). The 1938 Social Security Act was essentially a consolidation of
all that had gone before. There was some pressure for “insulation”, meaning in
effect, attempts to argue that New Zealand should become self-sufficient by
boosting local industry as much as possible. By 1939 the GDP was one third higher
than it had been in 1931, and the Depression was in the past. But the economy
began to falter again, and the national debt grew. Nash was forced to go to
London yet again in 1939 to ask for more credit.
The hard
economic reality implied here is that the Labour government could well have
faced the same fate at the Ward and Forbes governments, had the downturn
continued. What saved the Labour government and its reputation was the outbreak
of the Second World War, which called for its own austerities and made New
Zealand gear up in quite a different way.
What does this
detailed history (which I have deliberately dealt with in detailed fashion) add
up to?
It forces us to
question the received image of the Depression by showing that the governments of
1928-35 were not bumblers who did not come to grips with the crisis, but were
politicians who did the best they could in the circumstances. It was Labour’s
good fortune to attain power, with a huge popular mandate, at a time when
economic circumstances were already on the mend. Hence Labour was able to carry
through very popular welfare and other policies that had already been pioneered
by the governments that preceded them. When the Labour government also faced
(in its second term) an economic downturn, its attempted remedy was exactly
that which the Ward government had attempted in 1928. This is why McKinnon so
often uses the term “restoration”. Labour was not introducing something new. It
was “restoring” the New Zealand that had existed before the Depression.
Just a few
additional comments. McKinnon is to be applauded for placing the extremists of
the age in their appropriate perspective. The tiny Communist Party is mentioned
a number of times, especially in association with the UWM, and its vivid rhetoric
is noted, but its influence on events is shown to be virtually nil. Likewise
the New Zealand Legion, its importance inflated by at least one historian as
“New Zealand’s fascist moment”, is shown to be an ephemeral movement with vague
and waffling ideas, which quickly sank from view.
I would not be
an honest reviewer if I did not note that The
Broken Decade is not an easy book to read. It is data-heavy, its sentences
are long and often tortured in style, and in the week I slogged through it I
sometimes choked on the level of minute financial and political detail offered.
In short, it is a very academic book. For this reason, its view of New
Zealand’s Depression is not likely to displace soon the more familiar legends.
Even so, it does
the historian’s essential job of challenging superficial views of the past.